Network Working Group                                          G. Huston
Request for Comments: 1744                                        AARNet
Category: Informational                                    December 1994


                  Observations on the Management of
                      the Internet Address Space

Status of this Memo

  This memo provides information for the Internet community.  This memo
  does not specify an Internet standard of any kind.  Distribution of
  this memo is unlimited.

Abstract

  This memo examines some of the issues associated with the current
  management practices of the Internet IPv4 address space, and examines
  the potential outcomes of these practices as the unallocated address
  pool shrinks in size.  Possible modifications to the management
  practices are examined, and potential outcomes considered.  Some
  general conclusions are drawn, and the relevance of these conclusions
  to the matter of formulation of address management policies for IPv6
  are noted.

1.  Introduction

  The area explicitly examined here is the allocatable globally unique
  IPv4 address space.  Explicitly this includes those address groups
  uniquely assigned from a single comprehensive address pool to
  specific entities which are then at liberty to assign individual
  address values within the address group to individual hosts.  The
  address group is handled by the technology as a single network
  entity.

  At present these addresses are allocated to entities on a freely
  available, first-come, first-served allocation basis, within the
  scope of a number of administrative grounds which attempt to direct
  the allocation process to result in rational use of the space, and
  attempt to achieve a result of a level of equity of availability that
  is expressed in a sense of multi-national "regions" [1].

  In examining the current management policies in further detail it is
  useful to note that the IPv4 address space presents a number of
  attributes in common with other public space resources, and there are
  parallels in an economic analysis of this resource which include:





Huston                                                          [Page 1]

RFC 1744          Management of Internet Address Space     December 1994


   - the finite nature of the resource

     This attribute is a consequence of the underlying technology
     which has defined addressed entities in terms of a 32 bit address
     value.  The total pool is composed of 2**32 distinct values (not
     all of which are assignable to end systems).

   - the address space has considerable market value

     This valuation is a consequence of the availability and extensive
     deployment of the underlying Internet technology that allows
     uniquely addressed entities the capability to conduct direct end-
     to-end transactions with peer entities via the Internet.  The
     parameters of this valuation are also influenced by considerations
     of efficiency of use of the allocated space, availability of end
     system based internet technologies, the availability of Internet-
     based service providers and the resultant Internet market size.

   - address space management is a necessary activity

     Management processes are requires to ensure unique allocation and
     fair access to the resource, as well as the activity of continuing
     maintenance of allocation record databases.

  Increasing rates of Internet address allocation in recent years imply
  that the IPv4 address space is now a visibly finite resource, and
  current projections, assuming a continuation of existing demand for
  addresses predict unallocated address space exhaustion in the next 6
  - 12 years (rephrasing current interim projections from the IETF
  Address Lifetime Expectancy Working Group).  There are two derivative
  questions that arise from this prediction.  Firstly what is the
  likely outcome of unallocated address space exhaustion if it does
  occur, and secondly, are there corrective processes that may be
  applied to the current address management mechanisms that could allow
  both more equitable allocation and potentially extend the lifetime of
  the unallocated address space pool.  These two issues are considered
  in the following sections.

2. Outcomes of Unallocated Address Space Exhaustion - No change in
  current Address Management Policies

  As the pool of available addresses for allocation depletes, the
  initial anticipated outcome will be the inability of the available
  address pool to service large block address allocation requests.
  Such requests have already been phrased from various utility
  operators, and the demand for very large address blocks is likely to
  be a continuing feature of address pool management.  It is noted that
  the overall majority of the allocated address space is very



Huston                                                          [Page 2]

RFC 1744          Management of Internet Address Space     December 1994


  inefficiently utilised at present (figures of efficiency of use of
  less than 1% are noted in RFC 1466, and higher efficiency utilisation
  is readily achievable using more recent routing technologies, such as
  Variable Length Subnet Masks (VLSM) and disjoint subnet routing).
  Given the continuing depletion of the unallocated address pool, and
  the consequent inability to service all address allocation requests,
  it is a likely outcome of interaction between those entities with
  allocated address space and those seeking address allocation that
  such allocation requests could be satisfied through a private
  transaction. In this situation an entity already in possession of a
  sufficiently large but inefficiently utilised allocated address block
  could resell the block to a third party, and then seek allocation of
  a smaller address block from the remaining unallocated address space.
  The implication is that both address blocks would be more efficiently
  utilised, although it is the entity which has large blocks of
  allocated address space which would be the primary beneficiary of
  such transactions, effectively capitalising on the opportunity cost
  of higher efficiency of address block use.

  Such reselling / trading opportunities which involve the use of the
  unallocated address pool would in all likelihood be a short term
  scenario, as the high returns from this type of trading would
  increase the allocation pressure from the pool and act to increase
  depletion rates as more pressure is placed to claim large address
  blocks for later resale once such blocks are no longer available from
  the unallocated pool.

  Following exhaustion of the unallocated address pool a free trading
  environment in address blocks is a probable outcome, where address
  blocks would be bought and sold between trading entities.  The
  consequent market, if unregulated, would act to price address space
  at a level commensurate with the common expectation of the market
  value of addresses, trading at a price level reflecting both the
  level of demand, the opportunity cost of more efficient address use,
  and the opportunity cost of deployment of additional or alternate
  internetworking technologies to IPv4.  It is interesting to note that
  within such an environment the registry (or whatever takes the place
  of a registry in such an environment) becomes analogous to a title
  office, acting to record the various transactions to ensure the
  continued accuracy of "ownership" and hence acts as a source of
  information to the purchaser to check on the validity of the sale by
  checking on the validity of the "title" of the vendor.  This impacts
  on the characteristic features of Internet address registries, which
  effectively become analogous to "titles offices", which typically are
  structured as service entities with "lodgement fees" used to fund the
  action of recording title changes.  Whether existing registries adapt
  to undertake this new function, or whether other entities provide
  this function is a moot point - either way the function is a



Huston                                                          [Page 3]

RFC 1744          Management of Internet Address Space     December 1994


  necessary adjunct to such a trading environment.

  It is also anticipated that in an unregulated environment the trade
  in address blocks would very quickly concentrate to a position of
  address trading between major Internet providers, where a small
  number of entities would control the majority of the traded volume
  (market efficiency considerations would imply that traders with large
  inventories would be more efficient within this trading domain).  It
  is also reasonable to expect that the Internet service providers
  would dominate this trading area, as they have the greatest level of
  vested interest in this market resource.  This would allow the
  Internet service provider to operate with a considerably greater
  degree of confidence in service lifetime expectation, as the service
  provider would be in the position of price setting of the basic
  address resource and be able to generate an address pool as a hedge
  against local address depletion for the provider's client base.
  There is of course the consequent risk of the natural tendency of
  these entities forming a trading cartel, establishing a trading
  monopoly position in this space, setting up a formidable barrier
  against the entry of new service providers in this area of the
  market.  Such a scenario readily admits the position of monopoly-
  based service price setting. Compounding this is the risk that the
  providers set up their own "title office", so that in effect the
  major trading block actually controls the only means of establishing
  legitimacy of "ownership", which in terms of risk of anti-competitive
  trading practices is a very seriously damaged outcome.

  Assuming a relatively low cost of achieving significantly higher
  efficiency address utilisation than at present, then the resultant
  market is bounded only by the costs of agility of renumbering.  Here
  renumbering would be anticipated to occur in response to acquisition
  of a different address block in response to changing local address
  requirements, and the frequency of renumbering may occur in cycles of
  duration between weeks and years.  Markets would also be constrained
  by deployment costs, where local address trading within a provider
  domain would have little cost impact on deployment services (as the
  aggregated routing scenario would be unchanged for the provider and
  the provider's peers) whereas trading in small sized blocks across
  provider domains would result in increased operational service cost
  due to increased routing costs (where efforts to create aggregated
  routing entries are frustrated by the effects of address leakage into
  other routing domains).

  In examining this consequent environment the major technical outcome
  is strong pressure for dynamic host address assignment services,
  where the connection and disconnection of hosts into the Internet
  environment will cause a local state change in allocated addresses
  (which may in turn trigger consequent extended dynamic renumbering



Huston                                                          [Page 4]

RFC 1744          Management of Internet Address Space     December 1994


  from time to time to accommodate longer term address usage trends).
  It is also reasonable to predict a strengthening market for dynamic
  address translation technologies, as an alternate client strategy to
  the purchase of large address blocks from the trading market (this
  scenario is the use of a private, potentially non-unique address
  space within the client network, and the dynamic translation of end
  host addresses into a smaller unique Internet routed address pool to
  support external end-to-end sessions), and also the strengthened
  market for firewall boundary technologies which also admit the use of
  private address space within the client domain.

  While it is not possible to accurately predict specific outcomes, it
  would appear to be the case that increasing overall efficiency of
  address utilisation will be most visible only after unallocated
  address pool exhaustion has occurred, as there is then a consequent
  strong economic motivation for such activity across all the entire
  Internet address space.

  As perhaps a cautionary comment regarding evolutionary technologies
  for IPv4, it would also appear to be the case that evolutionary
  technologies will not assume a quantum increase in economic viability
  simply because of unallocated address pool exhaustion.  Such
  technologies will only lever additional advantage over IPv4 once the
  marginal cost of increased IPv4 address space deployment efficiency
  exceeds the marginal cost of deployment of new technologies, a
  situation which may not occur for some considerable time after
  unallocated address pool exhaustion.

3. Modification of Current Internet Address Management Policies

  The three major attributes of the current address allocation
  procedures from the unallocated pool are "first come first served"
  (FCFS) and allocation on a "once and for all" (OAFA) basis, and the
  absence of any charge for address allocation (FREE).

  As noted above, the outcomes of such a process, when constrained by
  the finite quantity of the resource in question, ultimately leads to
  a secondary market in the resource, where initially allocated
  resources are subsequently traded at their market valuation.  This
  secondary trade benefits only those entities who established a
  primary position from the unallocated pool, and it is noted with
  concern that the optimal behaviour while the unallocated pool exists
  is to hoard allocated addresses on the basis that the secondary
  market will come into existence once the pool is exhausted.  Such a
  market does not benefit the original address management operation,
  nor does it necessarily benefit the wider community of current and
  potential interested parties in the Internet community.




Huston                                                          [Page 5]

RFC 1744          Management of Internet Address Space     December 1994


  It is also noted that the outcome of a free address allocation policy
  is the vesting of the management of the address space to the larger
  Internet Service Providers, on the basis that in the absence of end
  client address allocation charging policies which have the capability
  of ensuring an independent address management function, those
  entities who have the greatest vested interest in the quality of the
  address allocation and registration function will inevitably fund
  such an operation in the absence of any other mechanism.  The risk
  within this scenario is that placing the major asset of any
  communications medium into the sphere of interest of the current
  entities trading within that medium acts to increase the risk of
  anti-competitive monopolistic trading practices.

  An alternate address management strategy is one of allocation and
  recovery, where the allocation of an address is restricted to a
  defined period, so that the allocation can be regarded as a lease of
  the resource.  In such an environment pricing of the resource is a
  potential tool to achieve an efficient and dynamic address allocation
  mechanism (although it is immediately asserted that pricing alone may
  be insufficient to ensure a fair, equitable and rational outcome of
  address accessibility and subsequent exploitation, and consequently
  pricing and associated allocation policies would be a normative
  approach to such a public resource management issue).

  It is noted that pricing as a component of a public resource
  management framework is a very common practice, where price and
  policy are used together to ensure equitable access, efficient
  utilisation and availability for reallocation after use.  Pricing
  practices which include features of higher cost for larger address
  blocks assist with equitable access to a diversity of entities who
  desire address allocation (in effect a scarcity premium), and pricing
  practices can be devised to encourage provider-based dynamic address
  allocation and reallocation environments.

  In the same fashion as a conventional lease, the leasee would have
  the first option for renewal of the lease at the termination of the
  lease period, allowing the lease to be developed and maintain a
  market value.  Such pricing policies would effectively imply a
  differential cost for deployment of a uniquely addressed host with
  potential full Internet peering and reachability (including local
  reachability) and deployment of a host with a locally defined (and
  potentially non-unique) address and consequent restriction to local
  reachability.

  It is also observed that pricing policies can encourage efficient
  address space utilisation through factors of opportunity cost of
  unused space, balanced by the potential cost of host renumbering
  practices or the cost of deployment of dynamic address allocation or



Huston                                                          [Page 6]

RFC 1744          Management of Internet Address Space     December 1994


  translation technologies.

  There are a number of anticipated outcomes of a management mechanism
  which including pricing elements for the IPv4 address space

  Firstly current address space utilisation projections (anticipated
  useful lifetime for the pool of unallocated addresses) would extend
  further into the future due to the factors of cost pressure for more
  efficient address utilisation, and the additional cost of issuing a
  local resource with a globally unique address and the opportunity
  cost of extravagant use of global addresses with purely local
  domains.

  Secondly dynamic host address binding technologies, and dynamic
  network address translation technologies would be anticipated to be
  widely deployed, based on the perceived cost opportunities of using
  such technologies as an alternative to extensive static host address
  binding using globally unique addresses.  Use of such technologies
  would imply further extension of the lifetime of the address pool.

  Such pricing practices could be applied on a basis of all future
  address allocations, leaving those entities with already allocated
  address blocks outside of the lease mechanism.  Alternatively such
  previous allocations could be converted to leases, applying a single
  management policy across the entire address space and accordingly
  levering the maximal benefit from such pricing policies in terms of
  maximising the lifetime of the address space and maximising the value
  of the address space.  In such a situation of conversion some level
  of recognition of previous implicit OAFA allocation policies can be
  offset through delay of conversion to lease and also through
  conversion of such previously allocated addresses to the lease,
  waiving the lease purchase costs in such cases.

4. Internet Environment Considerations

  Pricing for IPv4 addresses as a component of the overall address
  management framework is by no means a novel concept, and despite the
  advantages such pricing policies may offer in terms of outcomes of
  efficiency of utilisation, fair and equitable access, security of
  allocation and consequent market value, and despite the address pool
  exhaustion time offsets such policies offer, it is the undeniable
  case that no explicit pricing policies have been successfully
  introduced into the Internet address allocation processes to date.

  There are two predominate reasons offered in this analysis.  The
  first is the somewhat uncertain nature of the exact origin of primary
  ownership of the IPv4 address space, and the unallocated address pool
  in particular.  The address pool has been administered according to



Huston                                                          [Page 7]

RFC 1744          Management of Internet Address Space     December 1994


  policies drafted by the Internet Assigned Numbers Authority (IANA).
  The policies drafted by IANA are effectively policies which are the
  outcome of the same consensus seeking approach used within the
  Internet Standards process, and it is noted that within such an
  environment unilateral declarations of ownership and related
  assertions of policy control have difficulty in asserting an
  effective role within the Internet community and such declarations
  are generally incapable of gathering consensus support (It can be
  argued that "ownership" is not a relevant concept within this domain,
  as the essential attribute of such address elements are their
  uniqueness within the global domain, and such an attribute is only
  feasible through common recognition of a coordinated and reliable
  management environment rather than the historical origin of the
  resource in question).  Secondly there is no formal recognition of
  the address space as being a shared international resource which sits
  within the purview of national public resource management policies
  and administrative entities of each nation, nor is there a
  recognition of the address space as a private resource owned and
  administered by a single entity.

  Recent policy changes, whereby large segments of the unallocated
  address pool have been assigned to international bodies on a regional
  basis, with further assignment to bodies within national contexts,
  have been undertaken with a constant address allocation policy of
  FCFS, OAFA and FREE, and although some effort has been made to
  increase the deployment efficiency through explicit allocation policy
  enumeration, the general characteristics of address allocation are
  unchanged to date (those characteristics being of course FCFS, OAFA
  and FREE).

  One potential scenario is to speculate that pricing processes imposed
  by the address allocation agency are not feasible within the current
  Internet environment to the extent that any such policies could
  significantly motivate increased address deployment efficiency to the
  levels required for longer term unallocated address pool lifetime
  extension.  The lack of capability to employ pricing as a managerial
  mechanism, even to the extent of cost recovery of the allocation and
  subsequent registry maintenance function has a number of possible
  longer term outcomes:

   a) such functions will be restructured and operated from duly
      authorised national administrative bodies for each nation.
      Here the observation that the address pool delegation sequence
      within the current Internet environment has not to date been
      aligned with recognised national public communications resource
      administrative entities is an expression of the major problem
      that the unallocated address pool is not recognised as being
      intrinsically the same public resource entity as the radio



Huston                                                          [Page 8]

RFC 1744          Management of Internet Address Space     December 1994


      spectrum or the telephone number space.  The consequence of
      this mismatch between existing public resource management
      structures and IPv4 address space management implies that
      public operation for this activity on a national basis
      is not a commonly observed attribute.  The competency of such
      established public resource management structures in managing
      what continues to be a remarkably vibrant and dynamic
      technology-influenced domain must be questioned.  Potential
      outcomes may possibly include a rational and equitable address
      space management mechanism, but would also in all probability
      include a cost of a heavy damping factor on further
      technological innovation and refinement of the underlying
      technology base upon which the address space is sited as a
      longer term outcome.

   b) such functions are operated (and/or funded) by Internet Service
      Providers.  This is a more common scenario at present in the
      Internet IPv4 environment, and although such an operational
      environment does admit the potential for adequate funding for
      competent administration of the operation, the strong
      association of these entities who have established interests in
      the operation of enterprises based on the provision of services
      across the address space (i.e., strong interest in exploiting
      the address space) has a natural tendency to express domination
      of the market by established interests, threatening fair access
      to the common resource and threatening the open market of
      deployment of the technology.  It is reasonable to suggest that
      such alignments are undesirable from a public policy
      perspective.

   c) such functions are inadequately funded to service the level of
      activity, and / or administrated informally and consequently
      managed poorly, and the essential attribute of reliable address
      space management is not achieved.

  It is noted that these issues are largely unresolved within the
  Internet community today, and tensions between established and
  incoming Internet Service providers over equitable access to the
  unallocated address space pool are a consequent risk.

5. Concluding Observations

  In the absence of the capability to price the management of the
  Internet address space at administrative cost levels, let alone the
  capability to set pricing of address leasing at prices which reflect
  the finite nature of the resource and reflect (even in part) the
  market value of the resource, as a component of overall common
  address management practices, the most likely scenario is a



Huston                                                          [Page 9]

RFC 1744          Management of Internet Address Space     December 1994


  continuation of the FCFS, OAFA and FREE address management policies
  until exhaustion of the unallocated address pool occurs.

  It is perhaps a sad reflection of the conflict of short term
  objectives and longer term considerations that the evident short term
  motivations of ready and equitable access to the IPv4 address (which
  were the motivational factors in determining the current Internet
  address allocation policies) run the consequent risk of monopoly-
  based restrictive trade and barrier-based pricing as a longer term
  outcome of unallocated address space exhaustion.

  While free address allocation and the adoption of policies which
  include pricing components both ultimately produce an outcome of
  strong pressure for increased address space utilisation efficiency,
  the removal of the neutral presence of the unallocated address pool
  does induce considerable risk of open market failure within the
  Internet itself if free address allocation policies continue until
  pool exhaustion has occurred.

  Further strengthening of the current FCFS, OAFA and FREE address
  allocation policies, in an effort to induce higher address
  utilization efficiencies across the remaining address space is not a
  viable address management strategy refinement, in so far as the
  trading market will then commence before unallocated pool exhaustion,
  trading in large address blocks which are precluded from such
  strengthened address allocation policies.

  The most negative aspect of this are is that these processes will
  erode levels of confidence in the self regulatory capability of the
  Internet community, such that significant doubts will be expressed by
  the larger community the Internet process is one which is appropriate
  for effective formulation of common administrative policy of one of
  the core common assets of the Internet.

  These outcomes can all be interpreted as policy failure outcomes.

  The seriousness of these outcomes must be assessed in the terms of
  the anticipated timeframe of such policy failure.  Current
  expectations of unallocated address pool lifetime of 6 - 12 years
  does allow the Internet community some time to revisit their methods
  of administrative process definition, but this observation is
  tempered by the IPv6 process and by increasing levels of pressure on
  the address space in terms of growth in address demand through growth
  of deployment of the Internet itself.

  It is perhaps an appropriate conclusion to acknowledge the
  impediments of existing processes to admit any significant process or
  policy change that would produce a more efficient and effective



Huston                                                         [Page 10]

RFC 1744          Management of Internet Address Space     December 1994


  address space management regime.

  However it is this policy failure to efficiently utilise the IPv4
  address space through inadequate address pool management policies,
  rather than the exhaustion of the pool per se which is perhaps the
  driving force to design and deploy an evolutionary technology to IPv4
  which possesses as a major attribute a significantly larger address
  space.

  It is also appropriate to conclude that any outside observer of the
  IPv6 refinement process will look to see if there is any evidence of
  experiential learning in address management policies.  If there is to
  be a successor technology for IPv4 it would be reasonable to
  anticipate that associated address pool management mechanisms show a
  greater degree of understanding of public resource space management
  capability in the light of this experience.  If no such evidence is
  forthcoming then there is no clear mechanism to instil sufficient
  levels of consumer and industry confidence in such technologies in
  such a way which would admit large scale public deployment,
  irrespective of the technical attributes of the successor technology.
  Such potential mechanisms may include pricing components irrespective
  of the actual size of the address resource, given that the number's
  uniqueness is a resource with inherent market value irrespective of
  whether scarcity pricing premiums are relevant in such an address
  space.

  It is also appropriate to conclude that continuation of current
  address space management policies run a very strong risk of
  restrictive and monopoly-based trading in address space, with
  consequence of the same trading practices being expressed within the
  deployed Internet itself.

  The immediate action considered to be most appropriately aligned to
  both the interests of the Internet community and the broader public
  community is to examine Internet address space management structures
  which include pricing as well as policy components within the overall
  management mechanism, and to examine the application of such
  mechanisms to both the existing IPv4 address space, and to that of
  any refinement or successor Internet technology base.












Huston                                                         [Page 11]

RFC 1744          Management of Internet Address Space     December 1994


6. References

  [1] Gerich, E., "Guidelines for Management of IP Address Space", RFC
      1466, Merit Network, Inc., May 1993.

7. Security Considerations

  Security issues are not discussed in this memo.

8. Author's Address

  Geoff Huston
  Australian Academic and Research Network
  GPO Box 1142
  Canberra  ACT  2601
  Australia

  Phone: +61 6 249 3385
  Fax: +61 6 249 1369
  EMail: [email protected]































Huston                                                         [Page 12]