Network Working Working Group                           B. Kahin, Editor
Request for Comments: 1192                                       Harvard
                                                          November 1990


                  Commercialization of the Internet
                           Summary Report

Status of this Memo

  This memo is based on a workshop held by the Science, Technology and
  Public Policy Program of the John F. Kennedy School of Government,
  Harvard University, March 1-3, 1990.

  This memo provides information for the Internet community.  It does
  not specify any standard.  Distribution of this memo is unlimited.

Introduction

  "The networks of Stages 2 and 3 will be implemented and operated so
  that they can become commercialized; industry will then be able to
  supplant the government in supplying these network services."  --
  Federal Research Internet Coordinating Committee, Program Plan for
  the National Research and Education Network, May 23, 1989, pp. 4-5.

  "The NREN should be the prototype of a new national information
  infrastructure which could be available to every home, office and
  factory.  Wherever information is used, from manufacturing to high-
  definition home video entertainment, and most particularly in
  education, the country will benefit from deployment of this
  technology....  The corresponding ease of inter-computer
  communication will then provide the benefits associated with the NREN
  to the entire nation, improving the productivity of all information-
  handling activities.  To achieve this end, the deployment of the
  Stage 3 NREN will include a specific, structured process resulting in
  transition of the network from a government operation a commercial
  service."  -- Office of Science and Technology Policy, The Federal
  High Performance Computing Program, September 8, 1989, pp. 32, 35.

  "The National Science Foundation shall, in cooperation with the
  Department of Defense, the Department of Energy, the Department of
  Commerce, the National Aeronautics and Space Administration, and
  other appropriate agencies, provide for the establishment of a
  national multi-gigabit-per-second research and education computer
  network by 1996, to be known as the National Research and Education
  Network, which shall:

       (1) link government, industry, and the education



Kahin                                                           [Page 1]

RFC 1192           Commercialization of the Internet       November 1990


       community;
            ....
            (6) be established in a manner which fosters and
       maintains competition and private sector investment in high
       speed data networking within the telecommunications
       industry;
            ....
            (8) be phased out when commercial networks can meet the
       networking needs of American researchers."

  -- S. 1067, 101st Congress, 2nd Session, as marked up April 3, 1990
  ["High-Performance Computing Act of 1990"], Title II, Section 201.

Background

  This report is based on a workshop held at the John F. Kennedy School
  of Government, Harvard University March 1-3, 1990, by the Harvard
  Science, Technology and Public Policy Program.  Sponsored by the
  National Science Foundation and the U.S.  Congress Office of
  Technology Assessment, the workshop was designed to explore the
  issues involved in the commercialization of the Internet, including
  the envisioned National Research and Education Network (NREN).
  Rather than recapitulate the discussion at the workshop, this report
  attempts to synthesize the issues for the benefit of those not
  present at the workshop.  It is intended for readers familiar with
  the general landscape of the Internet, the NSFNET, and proposals and
  plans for the NREN.

  At the workshop, Stephen Wolff, Director of the NSF Division of
  Networking and Communications Research and Infrastructure,
  distinguished "commercialization" and "privatization" on the basis of
  his experience developing policy for the NSFNET.  He defined
  commercialization as permitting commercial users and providers to
  access and use Internet facilities and services and privatization as
  the elimination of the federal role in providing or subsidizing
  network services.  In principle, privatization could be achieved by
  shifting the federal subsidy from network providers to users, thus
  spurring private sector investment in network services.  Creation of
  a market for private vendors would in turn defuse concerns about
  acceptable use and commercialization.

Commercialization and Privatization

  Commercialization.  In the past, many companies were connected to the
  old ARPANET when it was entirely underwritten by the federal
  government.  Now, corporate R&D facilities are already connected to,
  and are sometimes voting members of, mid-level networks.  There are
  mail connections from the Internet to commercial services such as



Kahin                                                           [Page 2]

RFC 1192           Commercialization of the Internet       November 1990


  MCIMAIL, SprintMail, and Compuserve.  DASnet provides a commercial
  mail gateway to and from the Internet and commercial mail services.
  UUNET, a nonprofit corporation, markets TCP/IP services (Alternet)
  with access to the Internet as well as mail services.  Performance
  Systems International (PSI), a startup company which now operates
  NYSERNET (the New York State regional network, partially funded by
  NSF) is aggressively marketing Internet-connected TCP/IP services on
  the East and West Coasts.  RLG is selling access to its RLIN database
  over the Internet directly to end users.  Other fee-based services
  include Clarinet, a private news filtering service, and FAST, a non-
  profit parts brokering service.  However, in all these cases, any use
  of the NSFNET backbone must, in principle, support the "purpose of
  the NSFNET."

  Under the draft acceptable use policy in effect from 1988 to mid-
  1990, use of the NSFNET backbone had to support the purpose of
  "scientific research and other scholarly activities."  The interim
  policy promulgated in June 1990 is the same, except that the purpose
  of the NSFNET is now "to support research and education in and among
  academic institutions in the U.S. by access to unique resources and
  the opportunity for collaborative work."  Despite this limitation,
  use of the NSFNET backbone has been growing at 15-20% per month or
  more, and there are regular requests for access by commercial
  services.  Even though such services may, directly or indirectly,
  support the purposes of the NSFNET, they raise prospects of
  overburdening network resources and unfair competition with private
  providers of network services (notably the public X.25 packet-
  switched networks, such as SprintNet and Tymnet).

  Privatization.  In some respects, the Internet is already
  substantially privatized.  The physical circuits are owned by the
  private sector, and the logical networks are usually managed and
  operated by the private sector.  The nonprofit regional networks of
  the NSFNET increasingly contract out routine operations, including
  network information centers, while retaining control of policy and
  planning functions.  This helps develop expertise, resources, and
  competition in the private sector and so facilitates the development
  of similar commercial services.

  In the case of NSFNET, the annual federal investment covers only a
  minor part of the backbone and the regional networks.  Although the
  NSFNET backbone is operated as a cooperative agreement between NSF
  and Merit, the Michigan higher education network, NSF contributes
  less than $3 million of approximately $10 million in annual costs.
  The State of Michigan Strategic Fund contributes $1 million and the
  balance is covered by contributed services from the subcontractors to
  Merit, IBM and MCI.




Kahin                                                           [Page 3]

RFC 1192           Commercialization of the Internet       November 1990


  At the regional level, NSF provides approximately 40% of the
  operating costs of the mid-level networks it funds -- with the
  remainder covered by membership and connection fees, funding from
  state governments, and in-kind contributions.  This calculation does
  not include a number of authorized networks (e.g., PREPnet, and,
  until recently, NEARnet and CERFnet) that receive no NSF funding.
  However, NSF also funds institutional connections to the NSFNET,
  which includes payments by the institution to the regional network.
  Other agencies (DOD, NASA, and DOE) have also funded some connections
  to NSFNET networks for the benefit of their respective research
  communities -- and have occasionally funded the networks directly.

  Finally, the campus-level networks at academic institutions probably
  represent a perhaps 7-10 times larger annual investment than the
  mid-level networks and the backbone together, yet there is no federal
  funding program at this level.  Furthermore, since these local
  networks must ordinarily be built by the institution rather than
  leased, there is an additional capitalization cost incurred by the
  institutions, which, annualized and aggregated, is perhaps another
  20-50 times the annual costs of the mid-level and backbone networks.
  (These figures are the roughest of estimates, intended only for
  illustration.)

The NSFNET Backbone as a Free Good

  Whereas the NSF funding of mid-level networks varies greatly -- from
  0% to 75% -- the backbone is available as a free good to the NSF-
  funded mid-level networks.  It is also used free of charge by other
  authorized networks, including networks not considered part of
  NSFNET: CSNET, BITNET, UUNET, and PSI, as well as the research
  networks of other federal agencies.  As noted, their use of the
  backbone is in principle limited to the support of academic research
  and education.

  Through their use of the NSFNET backbone, these networks appear to be
  enjoying a subsidy from NSF -- and from IBM, MCI, and the State of
  Michigan.  BITNET and some agency networks even use the backbone for
  their internal traffic.  Nonetheless, these other networks generally
  add value to NSFNET for NSFNET users and regional networks insofar as
  all networks benefit from access to each other's users and resources.

  However, small or startup networks generally bring in fewer network-
  based resources, so one side may benefit more than the other.  To the
  extent that the mail traffic is predominantly mailing lists (or other
  information resources) originating on one network, questions of
  imbalance and implicit subsidy arise.  For example, because of the
  mailing lists available without charge on the Internet, three times
  as much traffic runs over the mail gateway from the Internet to



Kahin                                                           [Page 4]

RFC 1192           Commercialization of the Internet       November 1990


  MCIMAIL as from MCIMAIL to the Internet.  This pattern is reinforced
  by the sender-pays fee structure of MCIMAIL, which discourages
  mailing list distribution from within MCIMAIL.

  The impact of such imbalances is not clear.  For now, the capacity of
  the NSFNET backbone is staying ahead of demand: It jumped from 56
  Kbps to 1.544 Mbps (T-1) in 1988 and will go to 45 Mbps over the next
  year.  But NSF is concerned about a possible recurrence of the
  congestion which drove users off the NSFNET prior to the 1988
  upgrade.  Given the tripling of campus-level connections over the
  past year, continued growth in users at each site, the parade of new
  resources available over the network, and, especially, the
  development of high-bandwidth uses, there is reason to fear that
  demand may again overwhelm capacity.

  Offering the NSFNET backbone at no cost to authorized networks both
  encourages undisciplined use of the backbone and inhibits private
  investment in backbone networks.  It constrains the development of a
  market for commercial TCP/IP services by diverting an established and
  rapidly growing user base to a subsidized resource.  Charging NSFNET
  regionals and other mid-level networks for the use of the NSFNET
  backbone would resolve this problem, but this would impose a
  substantial cost burden on the mid-level networks, which would in
  turn have to raise membership and connection fees dramatically.  To
  compensate, the NSF subsidy that now underwrites the backbone could
  be moved down the distribution chain to the users of the backbone --
  i.e., to the regional networks, to the campuses, or even to
  researchers themselves.

  Each option poses unique opportunities and problems.  In theory, the
  further down the chain the subsidy is pushed, the more accountable
  providers will be to end-user needs.  Funding in hands of researchers
  would make universities more responsive to researchers' networking
  needs.  Funding in the hands of universities would in turn make
  regional networks more responsive and competitive.  And funds for
  regional networks would spur a general market for backbone services.
  But the mechanisms for expressing user demand upward through these
  tiers are imperfect.  And, from an administrative standpoint, it is
  easier for NSF to simply provide one free backbone to all comers --
  rather than deal with 25 mid-level networks, or 500 universities, or
  perhaps tens or hundreds of thousands of individual researchers.

Option: Funding Researchers

  It would be possible to earmark funds for network services in agency
  research grants as a matter of course, so that no new administrative
  process would be required.  But since network costs are presently not
  usage based, such funding will not readily translate into



Kahin                                                           [Page 5]

RFC 1192           Commercialization of the Internet       November 1990


  identifiable services and may simply end up in local overhead
  accounts since few institutions allocate out costs of access to the
  Internet.  The use of vouchers rather than cash add-ons might help
  ensure that federal resources are in fact applied to qualifying wide
  area network services -- and possibly avoid the imposition of
  standard institutional overhead on direct funding.  However, if
  vouchers can be sold to other institutions, as economists would
  advocate in the interests of market efficiency, these advantages may
  be compromised.  Even non-transferable vouchers may create a unique
  set of accounting problems for both funding agencies and
  institutional recipients.

  A federal subsidy channeled automatically to research grants could
  substantially limit or segregate the user community.  It would tend
  to divide the academic community by exacerbating obvious divisions
  between the resource-rich and resource-poor -- between federally
  funded researchers and other researchers, between scientists and
  faculty in other disciplines, and between research and education.
  Within the academic community, there is considerable sentiment for
  providing basic network services out of institutional overhead to
  faculty and researchers in all disciplines, at least as long as basic
  services remain unmetered and relatively low at the institutional
  level.  Of course, special costing and funding may well make sense
  for high-bandwidth usage-sensitive network services (such as remote
  imaging) as they become available in the future.

Option: Funding Institutions

  Alternatively, funding for external network services, whether in the
  form of cash or vouchers, could be provided directly to institutions
  without linking it directly to federal research funding.  As it is,
  institutions may apply for one-time grants to connect to regional
  networks, and these are awarded based on peer assessment of a number
  of different factors, not just the quality of the institution's
  research.  But redirecting the subsidy of the backbone could provide
  regular support at the institutional level in ways that need not
  involve peer review.  For example, annual funding might be tied to
  the number of PhD candidates within specific disciplines -- or to all
  degrees awarded in science.  Geographic location could be factored in
  -- as could financial need.  This, of course, would amount to an
  entitlement program, a rarity for NSF.  Nonetheless, it would allow
  institutions to make decisions based on their own needs -- without
  putting NSF in the position of judging among competing networks,
  nonprofit and for-profit.

  There are, however, questions about what sort of services the
  earmarked funding or vouchers could be used for.  Could they be used
  to pay the institution's BITNET fee?  Or a SprintNet bill?  Or to



Kahin                                                           [Page 6]

RFC 1192           Commercialization of the Internet       November 1990


  acquire modems?  For information services?  And, if so, what sort?
  Such questions force the funding agency to assume a kind of
  regulatory in an environment where competing equities, demonstrated
  need, technological foresight, and politics must be constantly
  weighed and juggled.

Option: Funding Regional Networks

  Shifting the subsidy to the regional networks is appealing in that it
  appears to be the least radical alternative and would only require
  allocating funds among some two dozen contenders.  Since most of the
  regional networks are already receiving federal funding, it would be
  relatively simple to tack on funds for the purchase of backbone
  services.  However, providing additional funding at this level
  highlights the problem of competition among mid-level networks.

  Although most regional networks are to some degree creatures of NSF,
  funded to ensure the national reach of NSFNET, they do not hold
  exclusive geographic franchises, and in some areas, there is
  competition between regionals for members/customers.  NSF grants to
  regional networks, by their very size, have an effect of unleveling
  the playing field among regionals and distorting competitive
  strengths and weaknesses.

  Alternet and PSI further complicate the picture, since there is no
  clear basis for NSF or other agencies to discriminate against them.
  The presence of these privately funded providers (and the possibility
  of others) raises difficult questions about what network services the
  government should be funding: What needs is the market now capable of
  meeting?  And where will it continue to fail?

  Experience with regulation of the voice network shows that it is
  inefficient to subsidize local residential service for everybody.  If
  one is concerned about people dropping off the voice network -- or
  institutions not getting on the Internet -- the answer is to identify
  and subsidize those who really need help.  The market-driven
  suppliers of TCP/IP-based Internet connectivity are naturally going
  after those markets which can be wired at a low cost per institution,
  i.e., large metropolitan areas, especially those with a high
  concentration of R&D facilities, such as Boston, San Francisco, and
  Washington, DC.  In the voice environment, this kind of targeted
  marketing by unregulated companies is widely recognized as cream-
  skimming.

  Like fully regulated voice common carriers (i.e., the local exchange
  carriers), the non-profit NSF-funded regional networks are expected
  to serve all institutions within a large geographic area.  In areas
  with few R&D facilities, this will normally result in a



Kahin                                                           [Page 7]

RFC 1192           Commercialization of the Internet       November 1990


  disproportionately large investment in leased lines.  Either remote
  institutions must pay for the leased line to the nearest network
  point of presence -- or the network must include the leased line as
  part of common costs.  If the regional network assumes such costs, it
  will not be price-competitive with other more compact networks.

  Accordingly, a subsidy redirected to the regional networks could be
  keyed to the density of the network.  This might be calculated by
  number of circuit miles per member institution or some form of
  aggregate institutional size, figured for either the network as a
  whole or for a defined subregion.  This subsidy could be available to
  both for-profit and non-profit networks, but only certain non-profit
  networks would meet the density requirement, presumably those most in
  need of help.

Increasing the Value of the Connection

  The principal advantage in underwriting the backbone is that it
  provides a evenhanded, universal benefit that does not involve NSF in
  choosing among competing networks.  By increasing the value of
  belonging to a regional network, the backbone offers all attached
  networks a continuing annual subsidy commensurate with their size.

  Increased value can also derived from access to complementary
  resources -- supercomputer cycles, databases, electronic newsletters,
  special instruments, etc. -- over the network.  Like direct funding
  of backbone, funding these resources would induce more institutions
  to join regional networks and to upgrade their connections.  For
  example, where a database already exists, mounting it on the network
  can be a very cost-effective investment, increasing the value of the
  network as well as directly benefiting the users of the database.

  Commercial information services (e.g., Dialog, Orbit, Lexis) may
  serve this function well since they represents resources already
  available without any public investment.  Marketing commercial
  services to universities over the Internet is permissible in that it
  supports academic research and education (although the guidelines
  state that such commercial uses "should be reviewed on a case-by-case
  basis" by NSF).

  But to date there has been remarkably little use of the regional
  networks, let alone the NSFNET backbone, to deliver commercial
  information services.  In part, this is because the commercial
  services are unaware of the opportunities or unsure how to market in
  this environment and are concerned about losing control of their
  product.  It is also due to uneasiness within the regional networks
  about usage policies and reluctance to compete directly with public
  packet-switched networks.  However, for weak regional networks, it



Kahin                                                           [Page 8]

RFC 1192           Commercialization of the Internet       November 1990


  may be necessary to involve commercial services in order to attract
  and hold sufficient membership -- at least if NSF subsidies are
  withdrawn.  Without a critical mass of users, commercialization may
  need to precede privatization.

Impact of Removing NSF Subsidy from the Backbone

  Any shift to a less direct form of subsidy may cause some disocation
  and distress at the regional network level -- until the benefits
  begin to be felt.  No regional network has yet folded, and no
  institution has permanently dropped its connection to a regional
  network as a consequence of higher prices, but concerns about the
  viability of some regionals would suggest that any withdrawal of
  subsidy proceed in phases.

  Moreover, as the NSF subsidy vanishes, the operation of the backbone
  becomes a private concern of Merit, the Michigan Strategic Fund, IBM,
  and MCI.  While Merit and the Michigan Strategic Fund are more or
  less public enterprises within the state, they are essentially
  private entrepreneurs in the national operation of a backbone
  network.  Without NSF's imprimatur and the leveraging federal funds,
  the remaining parties are much less likely to treat the backbone as a
  charity offering and may well look to recovering costs and using
  revenues to expand service.

  The backbone operation could conceivably become either a nonprofit or
  for-profit utility.  While nonprofit status might be more appealing
  to the academic networking community now served by the backbone, it
  is not readily apparent how a broadly representative nonprofit
  corporation, or even a cooperative, could be constituted in a form
  its many heterogeneous users would embrace.  A non-profit
  organization may also have difficulty financing rapid expansion of
  services.  At the same time, the fact that it will compete with
  private suppliers may preclude recognition as a tax-exempt
  organization -- and so its ability to reinvest retained earnings.

  Operation of the backbone on a for-profit basis would attract private
  investment and could be conducted with relative efficiency.  However,
  given the dominant position of the backbone, a for-profit operation
  could conceivably get entangled in complex antitrust, regulatory, and
  political struggles.  A nonprofit organization is not immune from
  such risks, but to the extent its users are represented in policy-
  making, tensions are more likely to get expressed and resolved
  internally.

  The status of backbone or regional networks within the Internet is
  entirely separate from the question of whether network services are
  metered and charged on a usage basis.  Confusion in this regard stems



Kahin                                                           [Page 9]

RFC 1192           Commercialization of the Internet       November 1990


  from the fact that the low-speed public data networks (SprintNet,
  TymNet), which are sometimes seen as competitive to Internet
  services, do bill on a connect-time basis.  However, these commercial
  services use X.25 connection-based packet-switching -- rather than
  the connectionless (datagram) TCP/IP packet-switching used on the
  Internet.  Internet services could conceivably be billed on per-
  packet basis, but the accounting overhead would be high and packets
  do not contain information about individual users.  At bottom, this
  is a marketing issue, and there is no evidence of any market for
  metered services -- except possibly among very small users.  The
  private suppliers, Alternet and PSI, both sell "pipes" not packets.

Privatization by Function

  As an alternative approach to encouraging privatization, Dr.  Wolff
  suggested barring mature services such as electronic mail from the
  subsidized network.  In particular, NSF could bar the mail and news
  protocols, SMTP and NNTP, from the backbone and thereby encourage
  private providers to offer a national mail backbone connecting the
  regional networks.  Implementation would not be trivial, but it would
  arguably help move the academic and research community toward the
  improved functionality of X.400 standards.  It would also reduce
  traffic over the backbone by about 30% -- although given continued
  growth in traffic, this would only buy two months of time.

  If mail were moved off the regional networks as well as off the
  NSFNET backbone, this would relieve the more critical congestion
  problem within certain regions.  But logistically, it would be more
  complicated since it would require diverting mail at perhaps a
  thousand institutional nodes rather than at one or two dozen regional
  nodes.  Politically, it would be difficult because NSF has
  traditionally recognized the autonomy of the regional networks it has
  funded, and the networks have been free to adopt their own usage
  guidelines.  And it would hurt the regional networks financially,
  especially the marginal networks most in need of NSF subsidies.
  Economies of scale are critical at the regional level, and the loss
  of mail would cause the networks to lose present and potential
  members.

The National Research and Education Network

  The initiative for a National Research and Education Network (NREN)
  raises a broader set of policy issues because of the potentially much
  larger set of users and diverse expectations concerning the scope and
  purpose of the NREN.  The decision to restyle what was originally
  described as a National Research Network to include education was an
  important political and strategic step.  However, this move to a
  broader purpose and constituency has made it all the more difficult



Kahin                                                          [Page 10]

RFC 1192           Commercialization of the Internet       November 1990


  to limit the community of potential users -- and, by extension, the
  market for commercial services.  At the regional, and especially the
  state level, public networking initiatives may already encompass
  economic development, education at all levels, medical and public
  health services, and public libraries.

  The high bandwidth envisioned for the NREN suggests a growing
  distance between resource-intensive high-end uses and wide use of
  low-bandwidth services at low fixed prices.  The different demands
  placed on network resources by different kinds of services will
  likely lead to more sophisticated pricing structures, including
  usage-based pricing for production-quality high-bandwidth services.
  The need to relate such prices to costs incurred will in turn
  facilitate comparison and interconnection with services provided by
  commercial vendors.  This will happen first within and among
  metropolitan areas where diverse user needs, such as
  videoconferencing and medical imaging, combine to support the
  development of such services.

  As shown in Figures 1. and 2., the broadening of scope corresponds to
  a similar generalization of structure.  The path begins with
  mission-specific research activity organized within a single
  computer.  It ends with the development of a national or
  international infrastructure: a ubiquitous, orderly communications
  system that reflects and addresses all social needs and market
  demand, without being subject to artificial limitations on purpose or
  connection.  There is naturally tension between retaining the
  benefits of specialization and exclusivity and seeking the benefits
  of resource-sharing and economies of scale and scope.  But the
  development and growth of distributed computing and network
  technologies encourage fundamental structures to multiply and evolve
  as components of a generalized, heterogeneous infrastructure.  And
  the vision driving the NREN is the aggregation and maturing of a
  seamless market for specialized information and computing resources
  in a common, negotiable environment.  These resources have costs
  which are far greater than the NREN.  But the NREN can minimize the
  costs of access and spread the costs of creation across the widest
  universe of users.













Kahin                                                          [Page 11]

RFC 1192           Commercialization of the Internet       November 1990


Figure 1.  Generalization of Purpose:

  Discipline-Specific Research            CSNET, HEPnet, MFEnet

  General Research                        early NSFNET, "NRN"

  Research and Education                  BITNET, present NSFNET,
                                          early "NREN"

  Quasi-Public                            many regional networks,
                                          "NREN"

  National Infrastructure                 "commercialized NREN"

  _______________________________________________________________


Figure 2. Generalization of Structure:

  Computer                                time-sharing hosts

  Network                                 early ARPANET

  Internetwork                            ESNET, NSFNET (tiered)

  Multiple Internetworks                  present Internet

  Infrastructure                          "NREN"


Workshop Participants

  Rick Adams, UUNET
  Eric Aupperle, Merit
  Stanley Besen, RAND Corporation
  Lewis Branscomb, Harvard University
  Yale Braunstein, University of California, Berkeley
  Charles Brownstein, National Science Foundation
  Deborah Estrin, University of Southern California
  David Farber, University of Pennsylvania
  Darleen Fisher, National Science Foundation
  Thomas Fletcher, Harvard University
  Kenneth Flamm, Brookings Institution
  Lisa Heinz, U.S. Congress Office of Technology Assessment
  Fred Howlett, AT&T
  Brian Kahin, Harvard University
  Robert Kahn, Corporation for National Research Initiatives
  Kenneth King, EDUCOM



Kahin                                                          [Page 12]

RFC 1192           Commercialization of the Internet       November 1990


  Kenneth Klingenstein, University of Colorado
  Joel Maloff, CICNet
  Bruce McConnell, Office of Management and Budget
  Jerry Mechling, Harvard University
  James Michalko, Research Libraries Group
  Elizabeth Miller, U.S. Congress Office of Technology Assessment
  Eli Noam, New York State Public Service Commission
  Eric Nussbaum, Bellcore
  Peter O'Neil, Digital Equipment Corporation
  Robert Powers, MCI
  Charla Rath, National Telecommunications and Information
               Administration, Department of Commerce
  Ira Richer, Defense Advanced Research Projects Agency
  William Schrader, Performance Systems International
  Howard Webber, Digital Equipment Corporation
  Allan Weis, IBM
  Stephen Wolff, National Science Foundation

Security Considerations

  Security issues are not discussed in this memo.

Author's Address

  Brian Kahin
  Director, Information Infrastructure Project
  Science, Technology & Public Program
  John F. Kennedy School of Government
  Harvard University

  Phone:  617-495-8903

  EMail:  [email protected]


















Kahin                                                          [Page 13]